16世紀(jì)的歐洲霸主、西班牙國王腓力二世是個借錢如流水,違約如便飯的君主,破產(chǎn)了好幾次。但熱那亞的銀行家們卻幾十年如一日地給他放貸,還賺到了錢,并能安然度過一次又一次債務(wù)違約,全然沒有今天的“金融海嘯”式?jīng)_擊。這是怎么回事?兩位經(jīng)濟史學(xué)家分析說,今天的銀行需要學(xué)習(xí)他們的策略。
測試中可能遇到的詞匯和知識:
Habsburg Spain 西班牙哈布斯堡王朝(1506-1700),西班牙是當(dāng)時的世界超級強國,統(tǒng)治美洲和半個歐陸,但無敵艦隊和三十年戰(zhàn)爭的戰(zhàn)敗讓其霸權(quán)沒落。
déjà vu (法語)似曾相識;舊事幻現(xiàn)
strewn[stru?n] adj.撒滿的,布滿的
snare[sne?] n./v.陷阱,捕獲
Genoese[,d?en?u'i:z] n./adj.熱那亞人,熱那亞的
Armada [ɑ:'mɑ:d?] n.無敵艦隊
state-contingent 狀態(tài)依存,在這里意思是,腓力二世借短債時與債主有共識,錢能不能還,是視情況而定的,即“對賭”式的。
galleon ['gæl??n] n.大帆船
Banks should learn from Habsburg Spain (720 words)
By Hans-Joachim Voth and Mauricio Drelichman
Investors in the volatile debt of Ireland, Portugal, Spain and Italy can be forgiven a sense of déjà vu. The history of sovereign debt is strewn with promises broken, creditors losing their shirts (and sometimes literally their heads) and, during defaults, economic malaise. So does the long, melancholy history of government borrowing offer any lessons for policy makers today?
Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff, in their classic study of eight centuries of financial crises, argue that the repeated folly of investors is the cause of sovereign debt problems. After a few good years, creditors forget the risks, lend recklessly, then end up snared in a default. The cycle soon restarts as new investors convince themselves “this time is different”.
At the dawn of sovereign lending, King Philip II of Spain – ruler between 1556 and 1598 of the only superpower of his age – signed hundreds of loan contracts. He also became the first serial defaulter, halting payments four times. The story of a powerful monarch able to convince creditors to lend as much as 60 per cent of gross domestic product while defaulting again and again offers useful insights into how the bargain can be improved.
Sovereign debt crises today “hurt” in three ways. First, when bond markets panic and yields rise in a downturn, taxes are raised and spending is cut. Austerity aggravates the slump. Second, a country’s banking system typically implodes. Third, the return to debt markets is often long delayed; state employees are sacked, contractors go unpaid, and the economic slump deepens.
By contrast, Genoese lenders to Philip II created a safe and stable sovereign borrowing system. It survived shocks such as the failed 1588 invasion of England with the Armada. Most bankers lent to the king for decades; no lender lost money in the long term. Financiers simply charged higher rates in normal times to compensate for the risks during crises.
When shocks hit – such as a combination of low silver revenues and a costly war against the Ottomans – debt contracts were not expected to be honoured to the letter. Renegotiations were concluded fast – in 12 to 18 months, compared with today’s average of six to seven years. “Haircuts” for investors, from 20 to 40 per cent, were moderate. Lending resumed promptly.
Even in normal times, lenders and borrowers shared risk effectively. A large fraction of Philip II’s short-term debt was “state contingent” – repayment terms and interest rates were automatically adjusted in line with fiscal conditions. In bad times – when the silver fleet from the Americas was small, say – the king either repaid less or extended the maturity of a loan. This avoided the need to let soldiers go unpaid.
Automatic loan modification enabled Spain to avoid negative feedback loops such as those seen in southern Europe today, with falling tax revenue leading to austerity and hence an even more severe slump. The ability to write state-contingent debt using an easily observed indicator of fiscal health, such as the arrival of a fleet, was crucial. In modern debt markets, verifiable indicators such as value added tax receipts, certified economic growth figures or world oil prices could be used as measures of fiscal strength.
The practices of the bankers, too, offer lessons for today. Loans were expensive and profits high. The Genoese absorbed losses easily because of their low leverage. Instead of borrowing themselves or taking deposits (as earlier competitors had done), they mostly financed themselves with equity. In addition, they sold the lion’s share of each loan on to other investors. Profits and losses were then distributed proportionately. During crises, everyone suffered, but no toxic concentration of risk threatened the bankers’ survival. In other words, risk transfers that failed during the recent subprime crisis worked well in the 16th century.
Repeated cycles of lending and default, contrary to common belief, are not a sign of bankers’ stupidity. Often, creditors have realised that “next time will be the same”, and prepared themselves accordingly. They have provided effective insurance to the sovereign, and absorbed losses with thick equity cushions. The age of the galleon produced effective risk-sharing and a stable banking system; the age of the internet and jet travel is failing to do the same.
The writers, who teach economic history in Barcelona and Vancouver
請根據(jù)你所讀到的文章內(nèi)容,完成以下自測題目:
1.What do we know about King Philip II's Spain?
A. It was the only superpower of the age.
B. Its debt-to-GDP ratio reached 100%.
C. Its Armada defeated England.
D. It lost the war against the Ottomans.
答案(1)
2.Sovereign debt crises today “hurt” in three ways, which one of them is not?
A. Bond yield rise and governments are forced to cut spending.
B. A country's banking system implodes.
C. Employees and contractors of the government lose money.
D. Foreign forces would enter and intervene.
答案(2)
3.What is the difference between the Spanish debt crisis of King Philip II, and that of today?
A. The debt-to-GDP ratio is significantly higher today.
B. Debt extension would be negotiated only today.
C. Unlike Philip's time, today's debt is largely mortgage debt.
D. Creditor have to accept a "haircut" in Philip II's time.
答案(3)
4.What is not Genoese bankers' "magic"?
A. The were fully aware and prepared for the possible default.
B. Their leverages are low and capital ratios are high.
C. They avoided the concentration of the risks and profits.
D. They take in huge sums of cash deposits.
答案(4)
* * *
(1) 答案:A.It was the only superpower of the age.
解釋:西班牙的債務(wù)/GDP比重達到60%(考慮到當(dāng)時的交通和財政手段,這絕對是個天文數(shù)字),它的無敵艦隊被英格蘭擊敗,它打敗了奧斯曼土耳其,從而獲得了整個地中海的霸權(quán)。
(2) 答案:D.Foreign forces would enter and intervene.
解釋:ABC都是文中提到的
(3) 答案:C.Unlike Philip's time, today's debt is largely mortgage debt.
解釋:C顯然與事實剛好相反,腓力二世可以用美洲運來的金銀抵押給銀行家,而今天的國債是純靠信用,無抵押的。 腓力二世的債務(wù)占GDP的60%,今天的西班牙是80%多,兩者并沒有數(shù)量級上的差距。債務(wù)展期和部分免除是當(dāng)時和今天都有的。
(4) 答案:D.They take in huge sums of cash deposits.
解釋:ABC都是值得今天的銀行學(xué)習(xí)的。他們非常謹慎,知道貸給國王有風(fēng)險,因此不會廉價借給他,而他們多是用自有資本而不是借來的錢去放貸,不會遇到擠兌和流動性危機。 另外,他們把貸款再分包一部分給別的投資者,自己不會過多地集中風(fēng)險和收益。
The Genoese absorbed losses easily because of their low leverage.與 Profits and losses were then distributed proportionately.這兩句話解釋了BC選項。